Introduction
Have you ever thought about how individual rationality may
lead to collective irrationality?
In essence, rationality, or rational choices, is about
making sensible and justifiable decisions
This article entails a discussion of the circumstances under
which the logic of collective actions implies that individuals will not
co-operate to overcome environmental problems and suggestions on how one could
change such behaviour. Collective actions should, by definition, mean the
collaboration of individuals to take actions to
solve
problems. However, individual rationality is what disrupts
the internal logic of (successful) collective action.
In a nutshell: individual rationality is the capacity by
which individuals make sensible and justifiable decisions. When individuals’
choices or actions by a majority of people lead to adverse results at a macro
level, we call it “collective irrationality”
The theories will be set out in light of real-life examples,
such as the refundable deposit system for bottles and beverages in the Nordic
countries, the 5p charge for plastic bags in England, and domestic waste
sorting. The examination of the efficacy of these campaigns will demonstrate
where the problems of collective action are to be found and suggests how one
might overcome challenges to the feasibility of these schemes.
A problem of
rationality
While there are different challenges in different parts of
the world, environmental challenges are global and need to be tackled through
global collective actions. Collective actions are actions taken as groups, of
all levels and sizes, in order to achieve a common goal. This article explains
how society, in common, may come together to act in a more environmentally
friendly way. Based on the presumption of a nation’s sovereignty in
policy-making
The collective action
problem
is an issue that arises when the necessary action to benefit a group creates a
conflict between the individual and the group interest, and the individuals
have an opportunity to act in their own interest. On the basis of the rational
choice theory, one assumes that individuals choose a course of action based on
what is more in line with personal preferences; potentially leaving the other
members of a group worse off than they could have been if that individual had
acted in a different manner
In
The Logic of Collective
Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups,
Olson (1971) argues
that organisations, states and/or nations are only able to perform a function
when the people have a common interest. In other words, larger groups will not
act in accordance with the public good unless the individuals of that same
group personally stand to gain something from the collective action.
While it falls outside the scope of the article and will not
be commented on any further, it should be pointed out that the political
opinions around environmental challenges are divided. This article is written
under the assumption of an acknowledgment of humans’ responsibility to protect
the environment.
As mentioned earlier, there is a presumption of nations
having sovereignty in policy-making, i.e. organising society. One may say that
the elected representatives of a democratic state have the power implement
policies and laws to control our behaviour and daily life. Today, the duty of
protecting the environment within a sovereign state has been entrusted to those
elected representatives of the county/borough/government, but a recurring issue
is that they fail to fulfil their environmental responsibility. Under the
assumption that humanity ought to protect the environment, it should in theory
be easy to solve the issue through the implementation of new policies and laws:
in practice it has its obstacles. Olson argues that the reasons for failing to
implement a protective scheme are various and complex: “administrative
proceedings and economic interest sometimes prevails over environmental
imperatives” (Olson, 1971, p.143). Olson further notes that “the enforcement of
environmental protection law is costly and cumbersome” (Olson, 1971, p.143). In
other words, due to a lack of funding and political constraints, which are the
major reasons why politicians often experience difficulties in enforcing new
environmental-protective schemes, one needs to look at the challenge from other
angles.
Before exploring the different tools one can use to overcome the collective
action problem, the basis of why it arises in the first place shall be laid
out. The collective action problem can arise in two ways: ignorance and/or
individual rationality. Ignorance arises due to a lack of information, or
willingness to seek such information, or because of misinterpretation of the information
given
The value of
co-operation
When it comes to collective action to solve environmental
issues, all citizens have two options; to co-operate or
not
to co-operate. It is, as I have mentioned, when choosing the
latter, that the collective action problem arises. The rationale behind
choosing the latter is in fact quite logical and can be explained through the
concept of the Prisoners’ Dilemma: there is a risk your own effort might make
little, if any, difference to the outcome, and therefore you fail to make the
effort. If ‘I’ were to co-operate and ‘everyone’ were to defect, ‘I’ would not
gain anything from co-operating, but rather lose. ‘I’ am dependent on
‘everyone’ to co-operate. Regardless of what ‘I’ do, ‘everyone’ must follow the
collective action if a positive outcome is to be achieved, and if ‘everyone’ is
to co-operate, what difference would ‘my’ defection make? Most likely little,
if any. Following this it can be argued that “unless the number of individuals
in a group is quite small, or unless there is coercion or some other special
device to make individuals act in their common interest, rational
self-interested individuals will not act to achieve their common or group
interest
”
(Olson, 1971, p.2). Even
though the goal, which here is to protect the environment, is a common good to
‘everyone’, meaning “that no one in the group is excluded from the benefit or
satisfaction brought about by its achievement,” (Olson, 1971, p.15) people have
a tendency to defect. While such individuals on one hand would like to obtain
the collective benefit from the collective action, they have no interest in
paying the cost of co-operating in order to achieve the collective good (Olson,
1971, p.21). These individuals are ‘free riders’, meaning that they are not
co-operating, but are still able to enjoy the benefits. To make it even
clearer, the theory will be applied to the actual collective action of the
depositing and recycling of non-refillable bottles and beverages in the Nordic
countries.
All the Nordic countries—Denmark, Finland, Iceland, Norway
and Sweden—have developed a nationwide deposit system whereby citizens receive
a reward for all bottles being returned after use. By having the citizens
recycle their bottles, the society is spared both from producing new ones and
requiring the destruction of the old ones: clearly beneficial from an
environmental point of view
Keeping in mind that ‘everyone’ is also an ‘I’ at some
stage, it is logical that ‘I’ will not benefit from co-operating if not
‘everyone’ chooses to co-operate. It is reasonable for ‘I’ to ask him/herself
why they should make an effort in keeping the bottles stored and make the
effort of taking them to the collection points if it will not make a
difference. Also, if ‘everyone’ were to co-operate, the scheme would be
successful regardless of what ‘I’ decide to do. Thus, it is easy for ‘I’ to
defect and when every ‘I’ does so, ‘everyone’ does, and the collective action
will fail.
Based on this, it is important that one must come up with a
practice making it beneficial for ‘I’ to co-operate regardless of what
‘everyone’ does.
There needs to be a
system by which the population will apply a
dominant
strategy,
offering the highest payoff, to each individual regardless of
other players’ actions. This in turn creates a
Nash equilibrium
, a situation which exists when there is no
unilateral profitable deviation for any of the players involved and any and all
actions become favourable for the environment (
Bernheim 1984)
.
In other words, regardless of what ‘everyone’ does, the strategy (i.e. the
actions) must earn the player (‘I’) a larger payoff than any other strategy,
for any other profile or other players’ actions.
The Nordic countries may have reached a reasonably good
solution
[1]
:
the governments have introduced an extra cost for beverages with bottles
suitable for the recycling-scheme mark. This extra cost is then returned to the
consumer when recycling the product at given collection points. In this way ‘I’
benefit from being cooperative regardless of what ‘everyone’ does. ‘I’ will be
rewarded
by getting money for returning
the items.
However, not all collective actions are open to the
opportunity of giving money back to those who co-operate. The clue is still in
creating a system where ‘I’ feel that ‘I’ will be rewarded regardless of what
‘everybody’ else chooses to do. The next section will take as an example the 5p
charge for plastic bags scheme in England.
The other way
around
In October 2015, there was a change of policy in England:
all shoppers are now to be charged 5p for every new plastic bag issued to the
customer by the shop
The idea of introducing the 5p charge was to motivate people
to choose
not
to take a plastic bag
when out shopping. Instead of grabbing a new plastic bag, or even
bags
, every time they go shopping,
the idea was that people would start bringing their own reusable bags. Five
pence may not seem like a lot of money and some might even argue it is too
little to have an influence upon people. However, previous schemes in the
United Kingdom have shown that it is quite effective. England is the last part
of the UK to introduce a 5p charge for plastic bags; Wales introduced the scheme
back in 2011 and it resulted in a remarkable drop of 71% in the numbers of
plastic bags used by consumers.
Northern
Ireland and Scotland followed in 2013 and 2014 and can also report at
significant drop in the numbers
The scheme is in essence the refundable system, just the
other way around. While 5p itself is not a large amount of money, one can argue
that ‘I’ get the feeling of being ‘rewarded’ by saving money when ‘I’ avoid
paying for a plastic bag while shopping. While this might make it seem easy to
motivate people to co-operate, not all collective actions are as easy to
implement.
Waste sorting
Domestic waste sorting is one of the less easy problems to
solve. Motivating people to follow the instructions cannot
always
be solved by either giving money, or making people feel as if they
are saving money. Waste sorting requires effort from each and every individual,
to enable waste collection services to recycle efficiently and, in most cases,
people cannot see the result of co-operating. One must solve the problem in a
different way. Colchester Borough Council has decided to penalise those who do
not co-operate. People are penalised in two different ways: either having the
rubbish truck refusing to pick up the trash until it is sorted correctly; or
being given a fine
Third parties
Civil society (used in the sense of non-governmental
organisations which manifest the will of citizens to improve society, for
example environmental charities or lobby organisations such as Greenpeace) may
reach people via mass marketing, which can be done in different ways.
Civil society is an essential pillar in a
democracy
Civil society has arguably used and still is using the
strength of public relations (PR) more efficiently than many governments. PR is
about communication with the public. However, the government is expected to
present a relatively unbiased view when cases or situations arise
A common approach, especially when fundraising, is creating
a direct link between the donation and a particular outcome, e.g. showing a
picture of polar bear with a heading saying, ‘donate to save this polar bear’.
Instead of emphasizing the threat to wildlife, however, an efficient angle can
be to make the public feel related or connected to the environmental threat by
concentrating on the danger to human life, making one think “
that could be me
”.
The next closest thing to
me
is
family
, and especially one’s children. In 2017, Greenpeace used
this as a tool in their campaign against plastic pollution and microbeads. As
explained in detail below, the shift from simply stating why today’s use of
plastic is harmful to the environment to describing how it is harmful to our
own, and especially children’s, health, triggered emotions and engaged more
people.
Civil society’s ‘war’ against microplastic has been going on
a long time, but it was not successful until recently. Greenpeace’s campaign
warning about the way the tiny plastic particles are making their way into
waterways where they are eaten by wildlife, created a huge public outcry. The
campaign made sure to emphasise that not only do plastic microbeads affect
wildlife, but that they are also ingested by us
and
our children via the food chain (Greenpeace, 2017). This public
engagement encouraged the UK Government to propose the strongest microbeads ban
in the world to date
Going back to domestic sorting of waste: if an individual
defect on acting according to the regulations, the dustcart will leave the
trash in the street, leaving it to the person defecting to
sort it out
.
The emotional distress one may experience by being the only
household in the neighbourhood with trash bags still in the street when coming
home from work may work as a motivation to sort the trash as the regulations
stipulate. The cost of sorting the trash from the beginning compared to the
distress of being ‘told off’ in front of everyone gives the incentives to act
in accordance with the regulations.
The power of the pressure from non-governmental actors also
has its effects on an individual level.
Tom Tyler (2006) argues that we obey the law not because we fear the
punishment, but firstly, because we respect the legitimate authority
and, secondly,
because people who go
against the grain of conventional societal message are often accused of being
troublemakers and the cause of the problem. Knowing that all your neighbours
would most likely have seen that you did not take the time and effort to follow
the common rules, how would that make you feel? The discomfort and distress you
may feel, combined with the respect you have for your neighbours, if not for
the authorities themselves, would most likely have an effect upon you.
Regardless of your caring about the environment or not, it is reasonable to
assume that you would start to follow the law and sort your waste
Seeking a purpose
It has been shown that convincing people to act in an
environmentally friendly way has its challenges. The logic of collective
actions has been laid down, and the collective action problem is concluded to
stem from
individual rationality.
However,
as I have shown, the problem of motivating and/or convincing people to
co-operate can be done through different tactics. Social actors/institutions
such as the government, interest and pressure groups, private persons and
smaller communities, such as religious groups, may be able to influence people
to change their behaviour and co-operate. Economic motivation, feelings or
ethics/morality are all factors or ‘tools’ that could, should, and are used to
influence people’s behaviour. Individuals need reassurance that their efforts
are not in vain, but actually can make a change.
References
Barrett, S. (1995)
The
economics of international agreements for the protection of environmental and
agricultural resources
. Rome: Food & Agriculture Organization of the
United Nations.
Basili, M., Franzini, M., & Vercelli, A. (2005)
Environment, Inequality and Collective
Action
. New York: Routledge.
Bentley, A. (1949)
The
Process of Government
. Evanston: Principia Press.
Colchester Borough Council. (n.d.)
Fixed Penalty Notice - Environmental Crime
. Available at:
http://www.colchester.gov.uk/FPN
(Accessed 31 October 2015).
Dahl, R. A. (2000)
On
Democracy
. Connecticut: Yale University Press.
Department for Environment, Food & Rural Affairs. (2017)
Environment Secretary pledges action on
ocean plastics.
Available at:
https://www.gov.uk/government/news/environment-secretary-pledges-action-on-ocean-plastics
(Accessed 1 September 2017).
Department of Environment, Food and Rural Affairs. (2018)
Carrier bags: why there's a 5p charge
. Available
at:
https://www.gov.uk/government/publications/single-use-plastic-carrier-bags-why-were-introducing-the-charge/carrier-bags-why-theres-a-5p-charge
(Accessed n.d.).
Environmental Protection UK. (2015)
Environmental Protection UK. Retrieved November 1, 2015, from Car
Pollution
. Available at:
http://www.environmental-protection.org.uk/committees/air-quality/air-pollution-and-transport/car-pollution/
(Accessed n.d.).
Geelmuyden Kiese; Infinitum. (2015).
Annual report 2014
. Available at:
http://infinitum.no/english/about-us
(Accessed 31 October 2015).
Greenpeace. (2017)
Microbeads
- We won!
Available at:
https://www.greenpeace.org.uk/microbeads-we-won/
(Accessed 13 November 2018).
Hardin, R. (2013)
Collective
Action
. London: Routledge.
Howell, D. (2015)
The
5p plastic bag charge: All you need to know
. Available at:
http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/uk-34346309
(Accessed 31 October 2015).
Lipschutz, R., & Mayer, J. (1996)
Global Civil Society and Global Environmental Governance: The Politics
of Nature from Place to Planet
. New York: SUNY Press.
Olson, M. (1971)
The
Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups
.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Taylor, M. (2000) ‘Media relations in Bosnia: A role for
public relations in building civil society’,
Public Relations Review
, 26(1), pp. 1-14.
The Northern Territory Environment Protection Authority.
(2014)
Environmental Impacts
. Available
at:
http://www.ntepa.nt.gov.au/waste-pollution/plastic-bag-ban/enviroimpacts
(Accessed 31 October 2015).
Tyler, T. R. (2006)
Why
People Obey the Law
. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Welrich, P. (2010)
Collective
Rationality: Equilibrium in Cooperative Games
. Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
World Wildlife Fund. (n.d.). Threats. Available at:
https://www.worldwildlife.org/threats/pollution
(Accessed 25 August 2017).
Copyright
statement
© Kristina Raulo
Enger This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0
International Licence (CC BY).
[1]
The author
acknowledges that the Nordic countries are not the only countries in the world
using this refundable system; but due to the scope of the essay and
accessibility of data the example is limited to the Nordic countries’ practice.