Introduction
Over many years, behavioural nudges have
been used as part of the government’s policy making decisions as well as been a
large topic of interest in behavioural economics. Behavioural nudges became a
topic of interest following the ‘publication of the best seller Nudge by Thaler
and Sunstein (2008)’ as mentioned in Bogliacino et al, (2016). It is defined as
any form of influence on an individual’s choice making. It is assumed that
these nudges allow people to ‘make choices that are rational, self-interested and
consistent’ (Leicester et al, 2012). There are indirect and direct forms of
nudges for example, exchanging sugary desserts for fruits is an example of
indirect nudge and warning drivers to drive within the limit to avoid a fine is
a form of direct nudge. A nudge can provide guidance for the individual to not
only
make a decision
but to also ‘behave in a
particular way’ (Nudge theory - Wikipedia, 2021). The concept of behavioural
nudges is that they provide ‘positive reinforcements’ when aiding individuals
with their decisions. The need for nudges arises from many theories, but most
importantly the use for it comes in handy when attempting to avoid market
inefficiencies. This ‘exist due to information asymmetries, transaction costs,
market psychology, and human emotion’ (Hayes, 2020). Government policy makers
use these nudges to achieve obeyance in sectors such as health, education, and
enforcement. We will explore these sectors in detail late on. Subsequently, we
will also be looking into successful and unsuccessful forms of nudges that have
been previously implemented. With this in mind, this paper will function by
providing the theories behind behavioural nudges, the need for it and whether
they have been successful so far.
Theory on behavioural nudges
A number of researchers have attempted to
understand the concept of behavioural nudges for numerous decades. As mentioned
earlier, the purpose of nudges is to improve an individual’s decision-making
process by providing extra information that can allow the said person to make a
better-informed decision. This can come in the form of advertising the
drawbacks of smoking and drinking or illustrating the disadvantages of an
unhealthy diet to name a few. There are few methods that have previously been
used till this day to better inform an individual. Policy makers utilise
schools and other educational institutes to set examples by educating younger
students of the benefits of healthy eating. They also implemented this rule
through the sugar tax which was introduced in January 2014 to combat the UK’s
obesity. An example of a positive behavioural nudge is when schools started to
provide fruits in place of sugary desserts. This change has created a positive
effect as it has allowed children to be healthier and parents to be more aware
of what their children are being served at school. Arno and Thomas (2016) also
pinpoint a similar finding that ‘items placed at eye-level in a supermarket may
be selected more frequently than those near the floor’ which further reinforces
a positive nudge. In contrast, as a result of Covid-19 and schools being closed
because of the pandemic, many children from low-income households have
unfortunately been neglected and consequently, statistics have shown that the
‘average intake of fruits...fell from just over one portion a day to half a
portion a day’ (Baraniuk, 2020).
Despite this it is also thought
that, in many cases according to Bogliacino et al, (2016) ‘behaviourally
informed policy interventions are complex and require new’ forms of
interventions unlike the neutral ones exhibited by Thaler and Sunstein (2008).
Furthermore, Fischhoff and Eggers (2013) as cited in (Bogliacino et al, 2016),
argue that behavioural nudges disregard the phases needed to implement a
positive behavioural insight. These most common assumptions in relation to
behavioural insight are that consumers are consistent, rational, and
self-interested (Leicester, et al, 2012). For example, they pay particular
attention to three methods needed: ‘normative analysis’ which utilises
available resources to predict the choice the individual would make. Secondly,
‘descriptive analysis’ identifies the decision an individual would make
predominately based on the policies that are existent. Lastly, ‘prescriptive
analysis’ embodies and distinguishes the ‘gap’ between both the normative and
descriptive steps taken forward. Despite this, there are also limitations to
this conviction. It can be disputed that despite policy makers researching and
nudging individuals to make a better-informed decision, ‘without knowing
individuals’ values, analysts cannot identify evidence relevant to their
choices’ (Bogliacino et al, 2016). In the next section, we will be exploring
the arguments for nudges and highlighting examples positive nudges.
Argument supporting nudges
As discussed earlier, the concept of nudges
has been given particular attention and many researchers have shown interest by
supporting the view that nudges are beneficial. The argument is whether ‘should
nudging be deemed as permissible... intrusive to individuals’ freedom of
choice?’ in Hagman
et al.
, (2015)
According to Schmidt and Engelen (2020)
nudges provide a freedom of choice without significantly changing any factors
that could contribute to disabling this freedom. The nudge approach plays
significance when policy makers create policies that require them to be
transparent as possible. In contrast, some argue that there is great concern
that too much freedom of choice may eventually ‘sidestep some partisan and
ideological disagreements that are so often beset politics’ (ibid).
On the other hand, behavioural nudges
created by policy makers can also be more welcomed if people felt their choices
were created ‘by parties with whom they can identify’ with in Hagman
et al.
,
(2015). Similarly, in the context of associating behavioural nudges with policy
implementation, it has been expressed that ‘there has been a shifted focus
toward using nudges to increase prosocial behavior’ which means ‘serving
society at large as opposed to the individual’. This view has been an
increasingly utilised method by policy makers to overcome inefficiencies when
setting policies. An example of an environmental (educative) nudge would be to
provide recycling bins to every household to set an example to recycle and to
achieve the goal of a green nudge. By ‘endowing individuals with resources in
order to enhance their capacity for reflective choice’ will facilitate
overcoming such biases. However, contrary to belief, while we may assume that
all individuals will obey to these rules, some decide not to and instead choose
‘to free ride and choose not to recycle’.
To support the above theoretical
perspective on behavioural nudges, an experiment was conducted in Hagman
et
al.
, (2015) research paper. The experiment was observed in both Sweden and
in the United States of America (USA). Both groups were presented with a set of
questions and examples to seek to under if these interventions restricted the
individuals in any way and if the policies were acceptable. The first set of
policies referred to as pro-social ranged from organ donation, climate
compensation, energy consumption and avoiding tax evasion. The second set of
policies were referred to as pro-self which were categorised as smoking
cessation, smoking discouragement, cafeteria re-design and food labelling. The
survey responses ‘on all four questions were given on a four-point Likert scale
ranging from 1 (not at all) to 4 (very much)’. The themes identified in these
responses are apparent in both Sweden and USA, where the policy on ‘food
labelling’ was highly accepted. A significantly positive result was found with
‘(86.9% in Sweden and 83.8% in the United States)’. Interestingly, they found
no evidence that ‘nudge-policies as intrusive to freedom of choice’ as
hypothesised earlier. With this in mind, policy makers can use such behavioural
nudges to overcome any issues that may be faced when individuals neglect or do
not identify with. When this is the case, policy makers adhere to ensure that
social welfare is met and thus it is ‘natural that nudges are used to do just
that’. Having said that, there are limitations to this experiment. The data
only used two countries and the ‘concept of “one-nudge-fits-all” is not
tenable’. Apart from nudges, other factors such as cultural differences can
also influence an individual’s decision.
Argument against nudges
While we have set an argument above
supporting the concept of behavioural nudges and setting examples of occasions
where they have been successful, nudging has also equally received few
censures. Critics question the ability of the nudging theory stipulating only
guidance. Some argue that nudging can lead to the loss of freedom of choice and
moral values. Hausman & Welch (2010) as cited in Schmidt and Engelen (2020)
claims that nudges in fact do not act as a form of guidance but instead ‘pull
our strings and employ tricks to get us to do what
they
want’. This
results in our choice not being completely of our own.
Perhaps the most interesting finding in
Schubert (2017) paper, is that ‘transparency makes most nudges somewhat less
effective, without, however, eliminating their impact’. As identified earlier,
transparency is key to avoid market inefficiencies as this is a result of
asymmetric information. According to Bruns
et al
., (2016), they believe
that ‘full transparency of nudges, thus, may even lead to the opposite outcome
than the one intended’. To an extent, this is feasible for example, a handful
people will attempt to understand the drawbacks of smoking and slowly quit.
Whereas few people will ‘protest against being manipulated’. In contrast to
this, according to Reisch and Sunstein (2016), their research found there was a
‘strong majority support for nudges’ from the six countries they studied.
However, they also mention that the same six countries ‘reject nudges that
offend’ any basic morals that are taken away from its citizens for example, the
government should not exploit its power and coerce money from its citizens
without their consent. It should also be noted that it is impossible for policy
makers to that they are completely aware of an ‘individual preferences
necessary to design optimal
nudges’
.
In summation to the above arguments,
Hirschman (1991) as cited in Sunstein (2017) holds the same view about
unsuccessful nudges. He claims that while policy makers may observe nudges to
have good intentions, it has shown evidence of being ‘futile’. For instance,
Hirschman (1991) proclaims that environmental nudges that are utilised to
reduce pollution may cause ‘increasing energy costs for the most disadvantaged
members of society’. Therefore, in the process of attempting to modify the
issue, nudges can ‘jeopardize’ this goal.
Relationship between nudges and overcoming
market inefficiencies
Leicester et al, (2012) discusses
extensively on the relationship between behavioural nudges and how to overcome
market inefficiencies/ failure. As mentioned earlier, market inefficiencies
occur ‘due to information asymmetries, transaction costs, market psychology,
and human emotion’ (Hayes, 2020). As a result of market inefficiencies that
occur in the economy, policy makers are constantly regulating this to ensure
that the any issues are kept to minimal. As a result of this, policy makers use
nudges as a form of intervention to overcome these problems. As discussed in
the previous section, behavioural nudges functions only as a form of guidance
to allow the individual to make a better-informed decision. In the case of
market inefficiency, whereby policy makers are tacking asymmetric information,
nudging may not prove to be sufficient. An example of an unsuccessful nudge is
the introduction of benefits to unemployed individuals – this essentially ‘can
reduce the effort people put into searching for jobs’ (Leicester et al, 2012).
Similarly, providing people with easier access to credit can also deter people
from managing their finances well. These are all examples of moral hazard – a
key concept in behavioural economics that highlights how individuals may engage
in behaviours that can be risky, but they are aware that they are protected by
a form of means therefore, do not restrict themselves from performing this
behaviour.
On the contrary, market failures are not
the only reason people engage in risky behaviours. ‘Social preferences might
mean people do not engage in more risky behaviour even when insured’ according
to (Leicester et al, 2012). Another perspective observed within behavioural
nudges, is the concept of ‘de-biasing’ which is essentially an attempt to help
‘alter these biases’ rather than recuperating the welfare. An example of a
positive nudge as a result of this, is the ‘alcohol strategy published by the
Home Office (2012)’. The purpose of this approach was to regulate the timing
that alcohol is served at, set a minimum price as well as ‘providing
information on the dangers of excess alcohol consumption’. While this strategy
sounds promising as it is transparent and can be effective. The issue here is
that ‘Packaging policies together like this might improve their overall
effectiveness, but... challenging to isolate the impact of individual policies
on behaviour’.
Leicester et al, (2012) also offer a
valuable insight into the advantage of using nudges. They state that nudges
‘change the behaviour of those who are ‘biased’ without imposing particular
costs on those who are not’. An example of a positive nudge in this scenario
would be the case of placing bans on cigarettes and the areas in which they are
smoked in. A ‘nudge-inspired policy might be to arrange some sort of private or
public mechanism whereby people can voluntarily commit’. By implementing this,
policy makers are essentially providing enough information by being transparent
to the people by creating an agreement with them. Conversely, if they fail to
oblige to the agreement, they can face a penalty that defeats the purpose of
not imposing a cost.
Conclusion
The purpose of this paper was to evaluate
how effective nudges are and how policy makers should utilise them to decrease
market inefficiencies in the economy. The evidence presented in this paper has
shown that nudges is a key concept in behavioural economics and useful as it is
transparent. The findings from this paper have demonstrated nudges are relevant
to an extent in providing guidance to individuals to make a better-informed
decision for example, educate a smoker on the harms of smoking or providing recycling
bins to increase recycling for environmental benefits. They are also cheaper to
administer. In contrast, few sources have displayed uncertainty when conforming
to the rules of nudging and if it may ‘jeopardize’ an individual’s decision by
eliminating their freedom of choice.